ImageVerifierCode 换一换
格式:DOCX , 页数:32 ,大小:165.76KB ,
资源ID:10491036      下载积分:3 金币
快捷下载
登录下载
邮箱/手机:
温馨提示:
快捷下载时,用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)。 如填写123,账号就是123,密码也是123。
特别说明:
请自助下载,系统不会自动发送文件的哦; 如果您已付费,想二次下载,请登录后访问:我的下载记录
支付方式: 支付宝    微信支付   
验证码:   换一换

加入VIP,免费下载
 

温馨提示:由于个人手机设置不同,如果发现不能下载,请复制以下地址【https://www.bdocx.com/down/10491036.html】到电脑端继续下载(重复下载不扣费)。

已注册用户请登录:
账号:
密码:
验证码:   换一换
  忘记密码?
三方登录: 微信登录   QQ登录  

下载须知

1: 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。
2: 试题试卷类文档,如果标题没有明确说明有答案则都视为没有答案,请知晓。
3: 文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
5. 本站仅提供交流平台,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。

版权提示 | 免责声明

本文(The longterm care problem precautionary saving and economic growth.docx)为本站会员(b****8)主动上传,冰豆网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知冰豆网(发送邮件至service@bdocx.com或直接QQ联系客服),我们立即给予删除!

The longterm care problem precautionary saving and economic growth.docx

1、The longterm care problem precautionary saving and economic growthJournal of MacroeconomicsVolume 29, Issue 1, March 2007, Pages 60-74doi:10.1016/j.jmacro.2005.04.001|How to Cite or Link Using DOICopyright 2006 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.Permissions & ReprintsThe long-term care problem, preca

2、utionarysaving, and economic growthNoriyoshiHemmia,KenTabatabandKoichiFutagamicaFaculty ofEconomics,Hokkai Gakuen University, 4-1-40, Asahi-Machi, Toyohira-Ku, Sapporo 062-8605, JapanbKobe City University of Foreign Studies, Kobe, JapancFaculty ofEconomics,Osaka University, Osaka, JapanReceived 10 D

3、ecember 2003;accepted 26 April 2005.Available online 22 December 2006.AbstractThis paper examines the interaction between decisions about financing after-retirement health shocks and precautionarysavingmotives, and how this interaction affectseconomicdevelopment. We show that at low levels of income

4、, individuals choose not to save to finance the cost of after-retirement health shocks. However, once individuals become sufficiently rich, they do choose to save to finance the cost of these shocks. This change in individualsavingbehavior may give rise to multiple steady state equilibria.Keywords:A

5、fter-retirement health shocks; Precautionarysavingmotives; Multiple steady state equilibriaJEL classification codes:E21; H24; O41Article Outline1.Introduction2.Individuals decision making2.1.Individuals optimization problems2.2.Decisions about paying for ARHS2.3.Thesavingproblem3.Equilibrium4.Conclu

6、ding remarksAcknowledgementsAppendix 1.AppendixAppendix 2.AppendixAppendix 3.AppendixAppendix 4.AppendixAppendix 5.AppendixReferences1. IntroductionThe cost of long-term care threatens the financial health of the elderly.1For example, in the USA, even with Medicare and private health insurance, the

7、risk of a catastrophic medical expense is large. Out-of-pocket medical expenses for the elderly in 1988 were estimated to be $2394 per elderly person or roughly 18% of their average per capita income. Nearly 10% of elderly households spend a fifth or more of their incomes on out-of-pocket medical ex

8、penses (Palumbo, 1999) and 23% incur medical expenses exceeding 40% of their adjusted gross incomes (Feenberg and Skinner, 1994). Nursing home expenses are the most significant long-term care costs for the elderly. According toPalumbo (1999), the likelihood of a typical 65-year-old person entering a

9、 nursing home during his or her lifetime is 43%. Once admitted, the average stay in a long-term care facility exceeds one year. Because nursing home costs are virtually uninsured, admission to a long-term care facility can quickly deplete ones financial wealth.Therefore, after-retirement health unce

10、rtainty should provide young individuals with strong precautionary motives forsaving.Despite this, less attention has been paid to this issue in the literature than to precautionarysavingin response to lifespan and earning uncertainty.Kotlikoff (1989)points out that the lack of research on this topi

11、c may reflect the difficulty of precisely quantifying theeconomicrisk of morbidity. However, recent analyses have begun to investigate this issue rigorously and they show that after-retirement health uncertainty has a strong impact on individual consumptionsavingbehavior. For example,Palumbo (1999)e

12、stimates that the uncertainty of future health expenses alone induces a typical family to spend, on average, 7% less. Furthermore,Hubbard et al., 1994,Hubbard et al., 1995andPalumbo, 1999show that the precautionarysavingmotives arising from future health uncertainty play crucial roles in explaining

13、the observed pattern of individual consumptionsavingbehavior over a life cycle.Recently,Dynan et al. (2000)found that higher (lower) lifetime income households are likely to save a larger (smaller) fraction of their income. This implies that there exists a positive correlation between lifetime incom

14、e andsavingrate. Considering the observed differences in precautionarysavingand bequest behavior by lifetime income groups,Dynan et al. (2000)explain this empirical result as follows. Concerning precautionarysavingbehavior, under the asset-based means-tested public subsidy programs such as Medicaid

15、and Supplemented Security Income, households with lower lifetime income are likely to reduce theirsavingsfor future health expenses so as to qualify for the subsidy program (Hubbard et al., 1995). On the other hand, households with higher (lower) lifetime income spend more (less) for medical treatme

16、nt in the case of costly illness (Newhouse, 1977).2Thus they are likely to save more (less) for future health expenses. Concerning bequest behavior, households with higher (lower) lifetime income are likely to leave larger (smaller) financial bequests to subsequent generations (Becker and Tomes, 198

17、6andMulligan, 1997). Therefore, the combination of these precautionarysavingand bequest behaviors may explain the observed positive correlation between lifetime income and thesavingrate.Caroll and Samwick, 1998andGourinchas and Parker, 2001, and others show that wealth that is held for precautionary

18、savingmotives occupies a larger fraction of total wealth and accounts for at least 50% of total wealth. Moreover, using OECD data,Jitsuchon and Saito (1995)show that cross-country differences insavingand per-capitagrowthrates are closely linked with the degree of heterogenous uninsured idiosyncratic

19、 shocks. These results imply that differences in individual precautionarysavingbehavior according to lifetime income may impact significantly upon the capital accumulation process of the economy. Therefore, it is important to investigate the relationships among after-retirement health shocks, indivi

20、dual choice of medical treatment, and precautionary motives forsavingin aneconomic growthcontext and explore the impact uponeconomicdevelopment.This paper establishes a simplegrowthmodel that explicitly incorporates the interaction between decisions to pay for coping with after-retirement health sho

21、cks and the precautionarysavingmotives. When an economy is underdeveloped, the cost of coping with after-retirement health shocks will prevent them from paying for it. In this case, paying for coping with after-retirement health shocks is not an effective option and people do not make precautionarys

22、aving.However, when the economy develops, people will decide to pay for coping with after-retirement health shocks. This paper shows that this positive correlation may give rise to multiple steady state equilibria in this economy, since higher income causes higher capital accumulation and vice versa

23、.This paper is organized as follows. Section2analyzes the interaction between financing decisions about after-retirement health shocks and precautionarysaving.In Section3, we present the dynamic properties of the economy and show that there exist multiple steady state equilibria. Finally, in Section

24、4, we summarize the results and suggest directions for future research.2. Individuals decision making2.1. Individuals optimization problemsIndividuals face a two-period dynamic programming problem. Individuals derive utility from their own consumption in both young and old periods of life, and have

25、no bequest motives. The utility function,u(c), satisfiesu0,u0, and the Inada conditions. Individuals are endowed with one unit of labor. They work inelastically in the young period and retire in the old period. In the young period, individuals allocate their labor incomewtto consumption andsavingst.

26、 Then, in the old period, they receive (1+rt+1)stand consume all the principal and accrued interest of thesavings.After-retirement health shocks (ARHS) are assumed to be unveiled in the beginning of the old period. Individuals suffer disutility(0) with probabilityp, and nothing with probability 1p.

27、Generally, even if any monetary resources are sacrificed, it is impossible to completely remove any disutility from being sick or handicapped. However, for simplicity, the effects of the shocks are assumed to be removed completely by paying the fixed cost ofdfor medical treatment.3If an individual s

28、uffers disutility(u(1+rt+1)st-d),the individual is not willing to paydfor coping with ARHS. On the other hand, if(2)u(1+rt+1)st)+u(1+rt+1)st-d),the individual is willing to paydfor coping with ARHS.Therefore, the individuals dynamic programming problem is as follows:(3)2.2. Decisions about paying fo

29、r ARHSIn the remainder of this section, we solve the optimization problem defined in(3). First, we consider decisions to pay for ARHS. FollowingFan (2001), we assume that there exists a lower bound on. This lower bound is defined by the following equation:(4)u(0)u(d)+.This reflects the fact that ind

30、ividuals do not paydfor ARHS if their incomes in the second period are less thand. Additionally, we defineas thesavinglevels, which satisfiesu(1+rt+1)s)+u(1+rt+1)sd)=0 givenrt+1. Thus, we have the following lemma.Lemma1 Decisions about paying for ARHSWhen individuals suffer disutility (0) in the sec

31、ond period, they decide to pay for ARHS if. On the other hand, if, they do not pay.ProofSeeAppendix 1.Note that, if. Thus,Lemma 1implies that individuals do not pay for ARHS, when they cannot save enough because of their low income.2.3. ThesavingproblemLemma 1states that individuals do not pay for ARHS, if. Thus, suppose that the inequality constraintholds in the first period, then(3)is rewrit

copyright@ 2008-2022 冰豆网网站版权所有

经营许可证编号:鄂ICP备2022015515号-1